Bem-vind@ - Benvenuto - Bienvenido - Bienvenue - Velkommen - Welcome - Welkom - Willkommen |
Jubilee South South http://www.jubileesouth.net |
The Development
and Historical Context of the Debt Crisis[1] Francisco
G. Pascual, Jr.[2] As
it was in ancient society when usury thrived under conditions of
widespread impoverishment on the one hand and the concentration of wealth
on the other hand; so does usury in modern society thrives under condition
of massive accumulation and concentration of finance capital coupled with
widespread underdevelopment. This is the situation in the world today. And
for as long as such opposite poles of concentration of wealth and poverty
is maintained the cycle of indebtedness continues.
How
usury thrives in such polarized situation is clearly demonstrated in the
case of the backward agricultural economies still prevalent in much of the
third world where usury still remains a major form of exploitation and
debt peonage a means of subjugation of a mass of impoverished peasants.
Usury and other forms of exploitation leave the peasant barely
enough for his means of subsistence; a situation that ensures his
perennial dependence on the moneylender. It
does not matter to the usurer whether the peasant had a good crop or not.
What matters to him is that debt is paid even if nothing is left for the
peasant's subsistence and, much less to improve his production. In fact, if misfortune befalls the peasant as in the case of
a bad crop, the moneylender would only be too willing to extend another
round of loans to the peasant to be paid after the next harvest. This
trick assures the moneylender a good share of the next harvest even before
the crop has even been planted. As
often happen the debt grows to the extent that it cannot by any stretch of
imagination be paid. Then the
moneylender can take possession of the land step by step until he fully
owns it. But even under these new circumstances he will not banish the
peasant from the land; he can make him a sharecropper and, as before,
still advance his subsistence and production needs as well. And the cycle
of indebtedness, therefore, continues but under more onerous terms and,
often, from one generation to the next. The
Debt Crisis: An Overview Modern
day international usury is, of course, much more complex than the more
primitive relation we have just presented.
Total Third World debt amounts to USD2 trillion; annual payments is
about USD 200million. The
system of debts has evolved into a key aspect of the capitalist economy; a
weapon for consolidating the domination of the people’s of the Third
World. In many ways, the debt today is a weapon more potent than others
devised by colonialism and neo-colonialism. It is institutionalized to a very
high degree, is regulated by a massive bureaucracy of the multilateral
finance institutions; and backed up by the military might of the mightiest
nations on earth. Worse the burden of paying debts is passed on to society
in general as a routinary process. Nonetheless,
the parasitism that is characteristic of usury is there and, in fact, far
more pronounced than in earlier periods of history. The modern
international finance oligarchy, in contrast to the industrial capitalist,
which dominated the earlier stage of capitalism, is completely detached
from production and entrepreneurial activity.
It makes billions in interest payments on the huge loans and more
so on speculative investments rather than industrial production. It has
created more financial instruments it abuses to the hilt. The big
capitalists are more into betting on financial instruments and
fluctuations in exchange rates than into improving production.
Modern
usury is based on a highly developed system of production, employing
science and technology to a high degree. Yet poverty is spreading even
official statistics must admit. Obviously
this is not due to scarcity of the means of human subsistence. On the
contrary, there is so much means of subsistence in the world today but the
problem of the big capitalists is how to sell the goods at a profit. For
the last two decades the world economy has been plagued with a chronic
crisis of over production. On the other hand, there is so much accumulated
capital while the opportunities for investment are shrinking.
Thus, this huge accumulated capital roams the globe to accumulate
more profits but in the process wrecks havoc on economies of the south and
east. It
is within this context that the debt crisis and the growing indebtedness
of the third world must be understood.
The onset of the debt crisis in 1982 was a manifestation of the
crisis of global finance capital. It simply means that the capitalist
trick of lending more and more money to the third world countries to
facilitate the sale of surplus goods and as a way of investing surplus
capital has its own limits. The injection of more loans (and other forms
of finance capital for that matter) to the third world has at best
provided only temporary relief, nay, postpone the recurrence of the debt
crisis only to flare up later in far more destructive ways. There has been
no real solution to the debt crisis. On the contrary, in the last few
years, the debt crisis flared up several times in ways more devastating
than at anytime in the past. The
IMF and the World Bank have turned the debt crisis into an opportunity to
arrogate for themselves unprecedented regulatory powers over, and at
certain times even get to micro-manage, economies of the Third World while
ensuring the profits of global monopoly capital. As monopoly finance is
confronted with its own crisis it "perfects" the institutions,
devise new tools, and create more favorable conditions for generating
profits and for intensifying exploitation and subjugation of Third World.
However, as has been shown by the recent crises in Asia, Eastern Europe
and Latin America, "neo-liberal"
schemes, improved or otherwise, lead to crises far more devastating than
previous ones. Before
we dwell on the historical development of the debt crisis let us briefly
go over the emergence of the monopoly finance which today controls the
commanding heights of the global economy. The
Rise of the Finance Oligarchy and the Export of Capital In
the last decades of the nineteenth century the free competition that has
up to then characterized capitalism in the industrialized countries gave
way to the dominance of monopolies. Monopolies have concentrated
production, divided the market among them, controlled the supply of raw
materials, bought or forced the submission of smaller rivals into their
"organizations." The ascendance of monopolies did not come
suddenly. This development was impelled by the internal dynamics of free
competition, i.e., the need for accumulation of larger and larger amount
of capital as the condition for survival in the fierce competition among
various capitals; and the cyclic and intensifying commercial crises that
came with capitalist expansion. Banking
was also transformed with banks assuming a new role. From their modest
role as middlemen in the making of payments, the banks grew into powerful
monopolies. A few big banks have taken over the place of numerous small
banks and have within their control, to mobilize for generating profits,
the whole capital of the society, of the big and small capitalists. At the
same time, the capital of the banks increasingly merged with industrial
capital, placing the banks in a more powerful position, over industry in
general. With merging of
industrial capital and bank capital, the finance oligarchy emerged;
finance capital has established its dominance over the capitalist economy. The
export of capital as opposed to export of commodities from the industrial
economies assumed particular significance.
Accumulation gave rise to surplus capital. Thus, capital flowed in the form of loans and direct
investments from the industrial to foreign countries because profits were
higher on foreign investments. In fact, in certain aspects (e.g. as a
percentage of GDP) [1], export of capital was higher then than in the
present era of "globalization." Then as now, the creditors were
often able to obtain "advantages", some extra profits like for
example a favorable clause in a commercial treaty, an order for guns or
ships, contract for construction of a harbor etc.
Britain
among several imperial powers took the lead. "As capital accumulated
in the hands of the wealthier class in Britain they found lending their
capital abroad or investing it in overseas enterprises to be more
profitable than investing it in Britain itself." But the rash in
lending and foreign direct investments reduced the available capital that
could have been used to upgrade industries in Britain.
Consequently, Britain's industrial production and manufacturing
lost pace with its rivals. "By the 1870's, British industrial
monopoly was lost, Germany and the US especially, were not ready to see
Britain's position of supremacy continue unchallenged.
Coming later in the industrial scene, they could take advantage of
more advanced technology, more modern factories, and little by little,
these countries began to out-produce and undersell Britain." [2] Uneven
development, the unceasing struggle for control of markets and raw
materials, and the crisis of overproduction would eventually lead to two
world wars among the imperial powers for a redivision of the world. The wars devastating as they were to the means of production
of countries that were involved brought enormous profits to monopoly
capital. In
the intervening period between the two world wars there was a vast
expansion of investments and concentration of capital through mergers and
buyouts of smaller enterprises. But this rapid expansion shortly led to
the crash in 1930. The western economies would recover after the
institution of some reforms but the "great depression" would be
resolved finally by another war. The
US was the biggest gainer in both wars, economically and politically which
to a large extent explains the present relative strength of various
capitals on a worldwide scale. The US emerged out of World War II as the
dominant capitalist power. Thus,
imperatives of US dominance over the capitalist world became the most
important factor in the political and economic development in the
"free" world in the post World War II era.
The phenomenal rise of the debt of the Third World with in two
decades after World War II is directly linked to the need for US capital
to continuously expand its markets through out the world.
The Accumulation of the Third World Debt Starting
with the American "foreign aid" drive in the years following the
war to the present regime of liberalized financial flows the debt of third
world countries has risen from USD9.7 billion in 1956 to USD 41.5 billion
in 1967 [3], USD 62 billion in
1970, USD481 billion in 1980 [4] to the present level of USD2 trillion.
So
rapid was this accumulation that by the 70s massive defaults threatened
the system. The massive infusion of new loans by the multilateral finance
institutions postponed the crisis by a decade. By 1982, the accumulation
of third world debt has matured into a full-blown crisis that threatened
the international financial system. The debt crisis since then has become
chronic. This development can be understood in the context of the
imperatives of US monopoly capital to expand its markets in the post war
period. The
American economy geared towards production for the war achieved phenomenal
growth during the war. Moreover, the war was fought in Europe and Asia
thus sparing the continental US of the physical devastation that other
capitalist powers suffered. Thus
the productive capacity of the US economy increased geometrically. For example the US at the end of the war accounted for 45
percent of the world's income, produced 60 percent of the manufactured
goods, in control of 70 percent of the oil supplies, produced 55 percent
of steel and other metals, one third of the world wheat. [5] US capital
was, therefore, confronted with the problem of disposing
the large stockpiles of military, industrial and agricultural
products generated by the heightened industrial capacity and the large
accumulated surplus capital to be disposed of was the problem of US
capital. Within
a few years after the end of World War II, a depression triggered by the
over-production of commodities threatened the US economy.
In October 1946, the Office of International Trade of the US
Department of Commerce estimated that "in 2 to 3 years US industry
would have saturated the domestic market with supplies." The only way
out was "to plan a decided expansion in overseas business."[6] But
the economic side of the picture presents only a partial view of the
realities the US was confronting at that time.
In political terms the US divided the world into "the free
world" and the "communist non-free world." More precisely
the identifiable political alignments in the post world war II period
were: (1) The US and other
capitalist powers (including Japan and Germany who were the enemies of the
allies in the war) and the underdeveloped countries that were under the
influence of the capitalist powers; (2) The Soviet union and the other
socialist countries; (3) The
non-aligned countries that refused to be controlled by either bloc
together with the strong national liberation movements in Asia, Africa and
Latin America. Given
the political and economic reality, US foreign policy was organized around
the twin objective of the defense of the "free world" or the
"containment" of communism together with the national liberation
movements; and the creation of markets for surplus US goods and capital.
Felix Greene (7) outlines the
imperatives for foreign policy in the period following the Second World
War thus: to keep the existing capitalist world capitalist; to find ways
to invest surplus capital abroad where the biggest profits can be made; to
find markets for American goods; to secure control over sources of cheap
raw materials; the establishment of unchalengeable military power. The
disbursement of "Foreign Aid" (the euphemism for loans and
grants) was linked to the politico-military and economic objectives.
Of the total USD115 billion 30 percent went to the developing
countries, 39 percent went to Europe and Japan, 31 percent to countries
that were in the periphery of the socialist bloc. Foreign aid was used to
entice and blackmail governments to toe the US line. Of course, should the
blackmail by the use of foreign aid and loans fail the US invariably
resorted to covert (coup, assassinations etc) and overt military
interventions from the numerous military bases all over the globe. The
first of the big loans the US extended in pursuit of the above objectives
were the Marshall and Dodge plans intended to "rehabilitate," in
fact, create the markets for American commodities in the devastated
economies of Europe and Japan. The
Marshall and Dodge plans benefited the US monopolies.
But unlike the loans to the third world there would be no
accumulation of foreign debt among the recipients since they were able to
build their industrial capacity and pay the debt and, in many cases, in
their own terms. "Foreign
aid" to third world countries (about 30 percent of the total USD115
billion) Europe would have the opposite effect. It initiated the process
of perpetual accumulation and dependence on the debt. From then on the
accumulation of third world debt was geometric and the only way by which
the system could continue was for debts to be continually recycled to
maintain the legitimacy of as well as the Third World’s dependence on
debt. The
fundamental cause of the perennial indebtedness is the inherently unequal
balance of trade between the predominantly agricultural and pre-industrial
economies of the third world and the industrial economies of the first and
second world. The third world
economies, fixed by the neo-colonial order to the production of raw
materials, agricultural products and low value added semi-manufactures
cannot earn enough foreign exchange to pay for capital and consumer goods
they must import from the industrial countries. More over since the 1980's
falling prices of primary products from the third world has resulted in
deteriorating terms of trade. [8]
Periodic devaluation of their currencies forced on them by the IMF/WB
makes exports cheaper (hence more exports to earn the same amount of
foreign exchange), and cause inflationary spirals in the domestic economy.
Hence, from year to year, the balance of trade and balance of payment
deficit deteriorate. This
chronic deficit in trade and the attendant deficit in the balance of
payments is only once in a while masked by extraordinary factors such as
the temporary rise in the prices of primary commodities, overseas
workers’ remittances (labor export), a surge in foreign direct or
portfolio investments. Normally,
however, the deficit is covered by the infusion of fresh loans to allow
the country to continue importing goods from the industrial countries and
to service the foreign debt. Ironically,
debt servicing, in conjunction with the remittances of profits by TNCs,
importation of luxury goods by the local elite etc. drains the local
economy of resources needed to industrialize and develop.
It is therefore fixed to the agrarian, pre-industrial level.
It is caught in a trap resuscitated periodically by the infusion of
loans and investments. In
the period of "aid and investment" the primary source of loans
for the third world countries were official development assistance budgets
of the industrial countries and the IMF and the World Bank. By the 1970s, however, commercial banks encouraged by the
IMF/WB and with large amounts of dollars in their hands, joined the action
in a large scale. For every dollar the IMF/WB invested into third world
loans it attracted 2-3 dollars from the commercial banks. [9] At this time
lending to the third world was attractive because prices of third world
commodities were rising which perpetuated the belief that the
underdeveloped economies would have no difficulty servicing their debts;
and interest rates for loans to the third world were high because it
allegedly entail high risks. More important is the fact that the
commercial banks believed that the IMF/WB would come to their rescue
should there be a danger of default. [10] Given
the above conditions the banks were emboldened to extend loans even to
dubious recipients and projects
such as the Bataan Nuclear Power Plant, which the banks knew, was Marcos'
milking cow from its inception [11].
All the actors in the lending scheme including the administrators
of apartheid in Africa to the military dictators of Latin America and the
autocratic dictatorships in Asia had their own roles to play to keep the
system afloat. Their corruption and indiscretion were part of the lending
system at this particular juncture in history but did not by themselves,
cause the rapid spiraling of the debt much less were its fundamental
cause. Of course, they were the frontliners in the "containment"
of communism and the national liberation movements as well as loyal
clients of international finance capital. And in the process too, they
enriched themselves at the expense of their own people. Through
out the seventies the IMF and World Bank too increased lending to the
third world to finance large-scale infrastructure projects (e.g. dams)
including prestige projects of autocratic and dictatorial regimes in the
third world. It also refinanced the maturing loans from the commercial
banks. Hence, loans from
these multilateral institutions grew rapidly and put them in a more
powerful position, vis a vis the debtors.
"The
over riding concern (in the increased lending) was not over the
sustainability of these loans but on expanding markets and political
stability for the US and its allies." [12] That is why in the late
seventies up to the eve of the Mexico triggered debt crisis in 1982, the
US, the WB and IMF kept calling for an increased lending to the third
world by the private banks. Of course, they were aware that unless there
is increased lending (up to 12 percent increase per year until 1985
according to the IMF and WB) the house of cards would collapse and the
system destabilized. In
1982, "Mexico blew the
whistle" that signaled the onset of the debt crisis. Mexico sought a
moratorium on payments and announced that it could not service its debt.
Subsequently and twenty-nine other countries at least expressed their
intention to seek a moratorium on debt payment.
For
over a decade the IMF-WB postponed this impending system's failure with
some degree of success by the massive infusion of new loan capital which
increased the indebtedness of the underdeveloped countries in a big way.
However, in the early eighties the inherent defects of the monopoly
capitalist system would manifest in the incapacity of many countries to
service their debt. There was
a recession in the industrial countries, which in turn dampened the demand
for third world products and prices of these products tumbled (and has
been falling ever since) which made the servicing of the debt difficult.
Moreover, because of the economic crisis the sources of new loans
to the third world also dried up. The IMF-WB came to the rescue but this
time with a whole package of conditionalities, which would open the third
world economies, more systematically, to the ravages of finance capital. Thus
began the push for "structural adjustment programs" ostensibly
to put the third world economies on "sound economic
fundamentals." Contrary to the avowed objective, however, SAPs only
deepened underdevelopment and indebtedness of the Third World. In reality
SAPs aims to open up the third world economies to international capital
while freeing government resources for debt servicing.
The
IMF/World Bank and SAPs In
the early 80’s the international finance institutions devised a
"new" system of lending that links loans to a whole set of
macro-economic reforms. The IMF/World Bank since then not only ensure the
servicing of all debts of the Third World to the Paris and London Clubs,
it also uses the debt as a leverage for putting into place the very same
economic policies that is at the bottom of the ever deepening
indebtedness. Structural
Adjustment Loans (SAL) or
loans tied to Structural Adjustment Programs are a "new
generation" of loans, which are tied to a set of macro-economic
reforms which aim to make the third world economies' import dependent,
export oriented and debt driven. Unlike conventional loans which have
specific objectives (e.g. a loan for the construction of a dam has the
objective of raising agricultural production for instance), SALs are
extended precisely to change macro-economic policy. Thus, SALs constitute
a new level of debt slavery of Third World nations by monopoly capital. These
destructive powers of the IMF/WB on the world economy as concretely
exercised in its imposition of the structural adjustment program (SAP) in
exchange for loans evolved with the accumulation of Third World debt and
the deepening debt crisis. For as long as the debtor countries recognize
the legitimacy of the debt, the coercive power of the multilateral
financial institutions over the client countries grow proportionately with
the debt. The
SAP is in accordance with the original purpose of the IMF and the WB but
is also a specific response to specific exigencies of expansion of the
market in the 80s and as capitalism was confronted with one crisis after
another. The
IMF and the World Bank were founded, in July 1944, one year before World
War II ended, when the US and Britain convened a conference of 44 nations
at Bretton Woods. The conference was called to chart a post war
international financial and monetary system in the framework of "open
and free market" as espoused by the US.
It was urgently necessary for the US to initiate this in
anticipation of the post-war capitalist rehabilitation and reconstruction
and the giant strides achieved by anti-capitalist forces in Europe and
Asia. Thus,
in what was officially called the "United Nations Monetary and
Financial Conference" the US, Britain and 44 other nations agreed to
"the establishment of two financial institutions - the International
Monetary Fund (IMF) and the International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development (IBRD) later renamed World Bank (WB). "The
conference also agreed on US Dollar-Gold standard, setting the value of
the US Dollar at $36 to the ounce and the value of other currencies
(except the British Pound Sterling that was also gold-based) are based on
the dollar." (On this
premise countries assumed that their Dollar earnings (reserves) have the
equivalent amount of gold deposited at the US Federal Reserves at Fort
Knox. This in fact instituted the US Dollar are the world's medium of
exchange.) Finally
the conference redefined "trade to include finance capital and;
instituted trade and finance liberalization through finance liberalization
and deregulation. Article VI (Capital Transfers) - state "member
countries may exercise capital controls so
long as it does not hinder trade." [13] The
Bretton Woods Conference also defined three main functions of the IMF:
"to administer a code of conduct with regards to exchange rate
policies and restrictions to payments on current account transactions; to
provide members with the financial resources to enable them to observe the
code of conduct while correcting or avoiding payments imbalances. "The
code of conduct was designed to ensure that payments for merchandize trade
and services and other current transactions could take place freely and
that all balances arising out of these transactions were convertible into
other currencies to be used to make payments
for further current transactions." [14] Of course, convertibility of currencies referred to in the code is
convertibility to the US Dollar - the de facto international currency -
and the liberalization of foreign exchange transactions. It
is clear that by design the IMF and the WB were to support the expansion
of US capital in the post war era the former specifically by providing
resources by which countries experiencing balance of payment difficulties
could balance their current accounts and thus continue importing goods
from the US; and, the latter, by providing long term loans for development
often times conditioned on the use of foreign materials and equipment and
the hiring of foreign technical consultants.
Loans were also tied to other "conditionalities,"
political and economic, the political consideration of
"containing" communism being significant at the height of the
cold war. In
the period of "aid and
investments," official development agencies - governments, the IMF
and the World Bank - were the main sources of loans. In the early
seventies, the commercial banks goaded by the IMF and WB came to the fray.
We must also recall that the IMF/WB, in the seventies, increased its
lending to third world countries by financing "mega-projects"
and refinancing the loans obtain from the commercial banks. Consequently,
the two institutions acquired and came to wield enormous influence and
power over client countries. The
process by which the IMF and WB came to acquire influence and power over
indebted countries is describe by Prof. Chosudovsky [15] thus: "Through
financial 'engineering' and the careful art of debt re-scheduling,
repayment of the principal is deferred while interest payments are
enforced, debt is swapped for equity and 'new' money is 'lent' to nations
on the verge of bankruptcy to enable them to pay off their interest
arrears on old debts so as to temporarily avert default, and so on.
In this process, the formal loyalty of individual debtors is
paramount. The creditors
accept to reschedule only if the debtor nations abide by the
'conditionalities' attached to the loan agreements." In
the early eighties, "a new generation of
'policy-based loans' was devised. Money was provided 'to help
countries to adjust.' The money was granted only if government complied
with structural adjustment reforms while at the same time respecting very
precise deadlines for their implementation… These loans were granted
subject to the adoption of a comprehensive program of macro-economic
stabilization and structural economic reforms… [and] were not in any way
related to a program of investment as in conventional project
lending." Moreover, the
implementation of policy reforms is tightly monitored by the financial
institutions and releases could be interrupted if the government did not
conform. "The
adoption of the IMF's policy prescriptions under the structural adjustment
program is not only conditional for obtaining new loans from multilateral
institutions, it also provided the 'green light' to the Paris and London
clubs, foreign investors, commercial banking institutions and bilateral
donors. Countries which
refuse to accept the Fund's corrective policy measures faced serious
difficulties in rescheduling their debt and/or obtaining new development
loans and international assistance. The
IMF also has the means of seriously disrupting a national economy by
blocking short-term credit in support of commodity trade."
Many
of the IMF/WB impositions in the structural adjustment programs have been
incorporated in the agreements in the WTO.
Thus, while the IMF imposes structural adjustment to 100 individual
countries simultaneously through "debt management," the WTO
completes the generalization of structural adjustments on an international
scale by providing the legal basis for these in international law. The
IMF, WB and the WTO in fact "regulate" the world economy in the
name of finance capital; and "manage" it through the deliberate
manipulation of market forces. They
force structural adjustments allegedly to enable countries to take
advantage of the "globalizing" economy but actually to create
the optimum conditions for the extraction of surplus by a handful of
finance capitalist from the whole of society in both the north, south and
now also the east. SAPs
invariably include two phases - phase one concerns the stabilization of
the economy and phase two is the implementation of structural reforms.
Phase one, economic stabilization includes devaluation, price
stabilization, and budgetary austerity. According to the WB, "Getting
macro-economic policy right…Keeping budget deficit small helps in
controlling inflation and avoiding balance of payment problems. Keeping a
realistic exchange rate pays off in greater international competitiveness
and in supporting convertible currencies." Phase two is a package
of reforms pertaining to trade liberalization, tax reform, and
privatization of government corporations. Devaluation
for its immediate and far-reaching consequences is the most important of
the package of policies in the "economic stabilization" phase.
Ironically, it destabilizes rather than stabilizes the economy.
It increases the debt in terms of the local currency, prices of
imports rise while those of exports drop; assets are deflated and become
very attractive for takeovers. Industries and enterprises devoted to production of goods for
the local economy are the worst victims of the rising cost of imports, and
lower prices of their commodities, credit crunch, rising interest rates
and the contraction of the market. The
impact on social classes and sectors are cruel
- unemployment, fall in real wages, rise in the cost of social
services, inflation and so on. The
empirical evidence showing the negative impact of structural adjustment is
overwhelming. But the World
Bank argues that these are "temporary pains" that society must
bear with for "longer gain."
When
the Asian crisis erupted and the prospects of long term gain from
liberalized economies permanently quashed, the IMF/WB argued that the
problem is of too little liberalization, lack of transparency or the way
structural adjustment was carried out not structural adjustment itself. On
top of this, their responses to the Asian crisis produced exactly the
opposite of the intended effect and were severely criticized even by
economists in the "neo-liberal" camp.
The
Debt Crisis Deepens under a Regime of Free Financial Flows In
1997, the Asian economies touted by the IMF and WB as model economies for
their adherence to the liberalization programs of the former suddenly
collapsed one after the other under the strain of huge short-term foreign
debt they suddenly found themselves unable to pay. In the process of
rescuing their distressed economies, they incurred a combined additional
debt of over a hundred and twenty billion US Dollars on account of the IMF
arranged "bail out." The
Asian financial is a debt crisis rooted in the same unequal trade between
the third world and the capitalist economies of the west, as well as the
crisis of over production of the world capitalist system but, however,
operating through the system of liberalized financial flows. Half of the
huge private debt due that year was incurred by banks and corporations and
was made possible in the first place by financial liberalization. That
the crisis broke out in the "growth area" and standard bearers
of the "neo-liberal model" of development unravels the extent to
which monopoly finance has become counter productive and shows the
destructive consequence of the debt crisis. How
did it happen? . The
"Asian miracle" was triggered by the influx of Japanese direct
investments in the Southeast Asian countries mainly Thailand, Indonesia
and Malaysia in the latter half of the 80s.
The influx was in turn due to the decision of Japanese capitalists
to evade the rising production cost in Japan brought about by the forced
appreciation of the Yen in the 1985 Plaza accords. Japanese capitalists put up production bases in the Asian
countries for the labor intensive production processes as well as the
environmentally destructive ones which they were after all being forced to
phase out in their home country. USD 15 billion in Japanese investment
flowed into the Asian economies between 1985 and 1990. By the end of the
eighties however these influx of Japanese FDI began to taper off. [16] To
sustain the inward flow of foreign capital and maintain the initially high
growth rates, the Asian "tigers" implemented a package of
policies designed to attract foreign capital in the early nineties. The
Asian governments implemented the policies of financial liberalization (no
control on the movement of capital); high interest rates; and a managed
float of foreign exchange (exchange rates were allowed to fluctuate only
within a given range). [17] Given the strong growth of the economies
initially spurred by the influx of Japanese investment, capital flowed
into the Asian economies to "catch the growth." In Thailand, in
the early 90's, about USD 50 billion move into the economy annually. With
the huge amount of accumulated capital, the falling rates of profits in
the industrial economies, and the fall of the Soviet Union and the wave of
privatization of state assets, there was more than enough reason for
finance capital to seek higher rates of returns in the "emerging
markets." A significant portion of the capital flowing in went into
banks and financial institutions which in turned invested into real
estate, which gave high rates of returns. By
the middle of the nineties, there was a sudden drop in the growth of
exports - Thailand for instance registered 22 and 24 percent growth in
exports 1994 and1995 respectively to zero growth in 1996 due to a glut of
commodities in the world market. Then real estate sector suddenly realized
that there were more properties it had developed than could be sold. Necessarily the real state companies defaulted on their loans
from the banks. In Thailand "with the bust in the real estate market,
the accounts in 1996…. Were seen as extremely worrisome. The foreign debt stood at USD89 billion of which 80 percent
of it was private debt and slight under half of which was short-term debt.
The net foreign exchange liabilities of Thailand's banks now came
to 20 percent of GNP. A massive debt crisis was in the offing, but unlike
the third world debt in the eighties this was one brought about not by
government borrowing but by private borrowing…” [18]
The
crisis was not totally unforeseen. The
1996 UNCTAD report warned of the dangers of high balance of payments
deficits the Asian economies were sustaining especially because "the
period of easy export expansion" was coming to an end. [19] In other words UNCTAD saw a weakening of exports thus generating a
balance of payments deficit which could trigger capital flight. Korea's
route to its own crisis was quite different. Korea enjoyed special
treatment from the US especially during the period of the cold war, it was
shielded by the military might of the US and its exports were given
preferential treatment in the US market. Japan was the primary source of
machinery and capital while the Korean State protected the industries as
well as "intervened" in the direction of economic development.
With this set of conditions, Korea developed a certain level of industrial
capacity so much so that in 1988 it enjoyed a USD6 billion-trade surplus
with the US. In
80's,however, the US now less concerned with the cold war and alarmed by
its massive trade deficit launched an offensive to reverse this trend. The
East Asian economies became the targets in this offensive. Japan and Korea
were labeled as "unfair traders" in the propaganda of the Reagan
administration and the US demanded that Korea and Japan take steps to
reduce their trade surpluses with the US including the appreciation of
their currencies to "cheapen" US exports and make imports from
East Asia more expensive. By
1996 Korea was sustaining a USD11 billion-trade deficit with the US. Korea
did not have a chance against this pressure.
Korean industry was dependent upon foreign technology, and more
over was based on the production of goods that were aplenty in the world
market - steel, ships, cars, computer chips, etc.
Moreover the chaebols, invested heavily in real estate which in
previous years was giving a higher rates of returns than industry and in
lines of industries that had "excess" capacity. By 1996 with the
drop in export earnings, Korea's current account stood at USD72 billion of
a total of USD110 billion external debt. Investors
knew the real situation in Korea (and East Asia) and the Southeast Asian
countries. With the precarious state of the balance of payments, panic
soon spread. Portfolio investments took flight, so with foreign exchange
that was parked in the banks simply taking advantage of the differential
in the domestic and foreign interest rates. Speculators joined in the raid
the of the foreign exchange reserves of the countries in crisis. Capital
flight and dwindling reserves put enormous pressure on the local
currencies that eventually led to their devaluation, Thus, was set off the
worst economic crisis in the post world war II era. The
raids on the foreign exchange reserves of the Asian economies would be
repeated shortly in Eastern Europe and Brazil. The
Asian crisis took the form of concurrent currency devaluation, collapse of
the stock market, and massive bankruptcies and tight credit.
This ultimately led to a recession of 40 percent of the world
economy. The whole economies are thrown back into previous levels of
development; a process called "thirdworldization" by some
economists. The social consequences include massive unemployment,
inflation, declines in real wages, and increasing rates of poverty. In
the latter half 1997 the IMF organized a "bail out" for the
three most severely affected countries in the crisis. The bail out is to save the banks and ensure that servicing
of the debt continues. Thus the private sector debt was conveniently
transferred to the public sector. In Korea of the USD72 billion short-term
debt USD 25 billion was paid from the bail out and USD 50 billion was
rescheduled but this time guaranteed by government.
The banks decide whom to let go bankrupt and whom to resuscitate.
Bankruptcies lead to takeover by foreign capital. The
creditors imposed new conditionalities to further liberalize of the
economy. [20] Meanwhile
in Eastern Europe privatization of state own enterprises led to a
large-scale transfer of industries to MNCs who by corrupting the
bureaucracy bought these at bargain prices and then mothballed the same
enterprises. Competition is
thus eliminated together with the potential for developing an independent
economy free from the dominance of global capital based on cumulative
gains these countries gained in the period of "socialist
construction." A very
recent article sent to the New York Times puts it clearly; "The International Monetary Fund and the World Bank
are successfully devouring Bulgarian industry. They have insisted on the
privatization of Bulgaria's plants and factories. In many cases, the
Bulgarian government, which diligently follows the IMF's advice, sold
these factories to powerful foreign corporations. And these corporations
often liquidated the businesses (a new way to fight the competition!). What is the result? Hordes of unemployed workers, beggars
in the streets, old people digging in rubbish containers for some rag or
moldy piece of bread. We are undergoing untold hardships, yet George Soros, the
financier, eggs us on, telling us to open our boundaries, make ourselves
an open society. But we in Bulgaria have learned the hard way what those
pretty slogans mean. It means killing the industry that is managing to
stay alive in Bulgaria. Turkish imports are flooding the market. Socks
made in Bulgaria are selling for 1 leva; I have seen Turkish socks,
selling for half a leva. So soon we will have only Turkish socks, and no
jobs. Lots of low-quality food products and other goods flow freely into
Bulgaria, undermining the efforts of local producers… What is the West offering us in return for this misery?
What is the great attraction for foreign corporation in a devastated
country? The cheap labor and national resources!
So much for open boundaries. So much for an open society." Such is the situation in Eastern Europe.
In Asia too, the means of production are laid to waste as these
countries are commanded by the banks to jettison "excess"
capacity. Asian industries are operating at a fraction of their capacity
[21] that is if they have not closed down completely. Occurring
side by side with this "dismantling" of the Asian and East
European economies is the concentration of the means of production into
bigger and bigger concerns in an effort to control a bigger share of the
market. Thus mergers are on the rise. Ironically "free market"
that is supposed to engender competition for the benefit of society is
producing exactly the reverse. Mergers are the trend in banking,
pharmaceutical, airline, biotech and other lines of industry. Just four
MNCs today control the pharmaceutical industry [22] and the recent bank
mergers are unprecedented in scale. In
the wake of the crisis, a new round of concentration of productive assets
occurs while economies of the south and east are push back, productive
capacity is destroyed while the people of these countries are denied of
their birth right over their economies.
Summary
and Conclusions: Break the Cycle of Indebtedness There
is no choice for the people of the third world but to break free from the
cycle of indebtedness. The debt crisis is linked to the crisis of the
global capitalist system and is bound to worsen as the crisis of the
system deepens. The present level of the third world debt cannot be
serviced by the underdeveloped countries. New loans only postpone the day
of reckoning, increase the debt burden, lay the grounds for worse crisis
in the future and serve to tighten the control of finance capital over
economies of the third world. In struggling against the debt we must at
the same strike at its very roots - monopoly capitalist rule over the
world economy. It
will not be enough to call for "debt relief" and more so when
these are conditioned on the very same economic policies that exacerbates
indebtedness. Debt relief schemes at best are publicity stunts to draw
away attention from the real causes of the debt.
When debt relief is conditioned on the installation of the very
policies that recreate the conditions, which breeds the debt problem then
it is an insult to the victims of the debt.
So
is it with such deceptive schemes as "debt swaps" that, while
ostensibly providing funds for some objectives that are beneficial to the
people - credit, protection of the environment etc. - nevertheless mask
the basic nature of the debt problem which is the systematic exploitation
of the third world through institutionalized usury. Indeed
the discourse on the debt must be enlightened by a thorough going analysis
of the system that breeds this problem.
The debt crisis is a systemic crisis and we must link our critique
of the unjust international economic system; our critique of debt peonage
must be linked to our critique of the monopoly capitalist system. As we in
the Jubilee South often say that the debt problem is an excellent window
to the unequal relations in the international economy. The
call for unconditional cancellation of the third world debt is a just
demand. It is just for the third world to demand this and be relieve of
the burden of servicing the debt. It is also necessary to call on or exert
pressure on the governments of the Third world to repudiate the debt
unilaterally. Indeed the third world "owes" nothing to the first
world. These
demands challenge the legitimacy of the debt. Such challenge is even more
important because of the fact that the ever tightening
"conditionalities" that go with the ever deepening indebtedness
is based on a recognition of the legitimacy of the debt. That it is
illegitimate is proved by the historical circumstances under which it was
incurred - apartheid, dictatorship, kleptocracy etc. Most important the
debt is based on an unjust exploitative system that systematically
appropriates the wealth created by the third world for a few financial
oligarchs. We
are often told that the discredited regimes of the past are responsible
for the burgeoning of the debt. Of
course they played their part in the system of debt during their despotic
rule and enriched themselves in the process.
But the "democratic" regimes that replaced them through
various "people power revolutions" have brought their countries
far deeper into indebtedness than their despotic predecessors and are even
more avid supporters of the "neo-liberal" agenda of finance
capital. There must be recognition of the fact that the economic interest
of the elites of the third world, be they of the "autocratic or
democratic type," is aligned with that of the international finance
oligarchy. It
is not enough to simply go back to some worn out model of the past, and
recycle this into the present or even to pick certain aspects of it and
graft it to the present model. For
the third world to break the cycle of indebtedness there must be a radical
break from the present import dependent, export oriented, and debt driven
economy. The economy must be reoriented to providing for the needs of the
local population rather than the international market, a determined thrust
to break import dependence by developing industry. There
must be economic reforms. The
current monopoly of land in many third world countries must be broken. The
commanding heights of the economy should be taken over by the democratic
state so that the whole economy can be directed for the people. We
have to build the movement against the debt at every level and link this
to the movements seeking to put an end to the "neo-liberal"
order and the whole rule of the finance oligarchy.
We have to place special importance to the national movements and
in doing so we build the necessary political strength to confront the
unjust system. Let us also build international solidarity to amplify our
efforts. We must not fall into the trap of chasing the international
institutions in every summit in the hope of getting some small concessions
not unlike morsels after the finance oligarchy are done with their feast. The
national level presents to us the weak link in the rule of global finance
capital because it is here where we build the real political strength. The
elite of the Third World countries must be made to account for their
responsibility in the debt crisis and the whole “neo-liberal”
onslaught on the people. We
are certain that this unjust social order must come to an end as others
before it came to an end. Certainly,
the people will bring it to an end.
________________ [1] Paper presented at the Jubilee South Summit, November 18-21, 1999, Johannesburg South Africa [2] Executive Director , Resource Center for People's Development RCPD, Philippines. RCPD is the secretariat of the Philippines Asia Jubilee Campaign against the Debt (PAJCAD).
|