World Investment Report 1998:
Trends and Determinants
Chapter III
Investment Policy Issues
Full text Adobe .pdf
format. (800k)
(...) It is generally accepted that one of the most important effects of tax treaties
is the legal certainty they provide to investors, in both the home and the host countries.
Regardless of any changes affecting a host countrys tax system, foreign investors
cannot be taxed beyond the levels allowed by a treaty. This effect is less comprehensive
in the home country. In reality, certain changes in the home country tax system can affect
the investor regardless of the existence of a treaty. For example, if the treaty provides
for the credit method, a general increase in the corporate tax rate in the home country
will also affect a resident deriving foreign-source income, regardless of the treaty.
However, the exemption method, if adopted in the treaty, could not be modified at will by
the home country.
Tax treaties can have development implications and cannot, therefore, be fully
separated from the context of various monetary, fiscal, social and other policies of
contracting parties. When the parties are at the same or a similar level of development,
the gain or loss of revenue resulting from reciprocal flows of investment does not have
the same significance as when the parties are at different stages of development. The
presumption of symmetries of gains and losses underlying tax treaties between countries at
the same level of development is not applicable for countries at different stages of
development. The loss of revenue may have a different value for a contracting
party, depending on its level of development. For this reason, it could be argued that any
eventual reduction in tax revenue from locally produced income should be offset by an
increase in investment and technology flows. Since income flows are generally from
developing to developed countries, a pattern of tax treaties in which the source country
gives up revenue more often than not will not involve the rough symmetry of sacrifice
which it might in tax treaties between developed countries. It should also be noted that
developing countries, in their domestic laws, often introduce measures aimed at the
alleviation of the tax burden of foreign investors, through a variety of tax incentives
including income-tax exemptions, reduction or exemption of export proceeds, and reduction
or exemptions of individual income taxes for foreign personnel. The benefits of these tax
incentives for investors may exceed those resulting from tax treaties. These benefits are,
however, offered unilaterally rather than in the context of an international agreement and
it may be that foreign investors will value more highly the benefits of more modest
reductions or exemptions given in the context of tax treaties with the attendant
advantages of stability, transparency and certainty of treatment. From the perspective of
host countries, having a smaller share of revenue, as a consequence of concessions offered
either in domestic legislation or in the context of a tax treaty, could be (though it need
not be) compensated for by increased flows of capital and technology into their economies
as the result of an improved climate for FDI.
A number of different views have been expressed on the role that the tax factor plays
in attracting or inhibiting FDI (Plasschaert, 1994, pp. 46-47). Although this factor
remains subsidiary to other factors, it is also generally accepted that, with the removal
of barriers to FDI, taxation may gain more importance in investors decisions.
Long-term investors may attach more importance to the general features of a countrys
tax system than to its temporary incentives. In considering the role of the tax factor in
attracting or inhibiting FDI, it may be important to distinguish the significance of
incentives from that of other features of the tax system such as stability, transparency
and certainty of treatment. Still, other things being equal, the tax factor could play a
determining role in the choice of an FDI location and this in turn could give rise to a
tax competition for investment (OECD, 1998b) (box III.12). (...) |
|